Jeffrey Sachs on Charter Cities and How to Reform Graduate Economics Education
Want to listen along? Here’s the episode – https://share.snipd.com/episode/dc65bbc7-e130-418e-a3ab-ca06c7f04a55 Mandatory full disclosure: I’m not an economist. My understanding of global development comes from Tik Tok and feeling guilty about my Amazon purchases. I once tried to explain comparative advantage at a dinner party and ended up discussing expensing my coffee. So take everything here with a grain of salt – preferably not the kind that economists would use to create market efficiencies. Grab your favorite beverage (I recommend caffeine – economic theory puts most normal humans to sleep) and let’s explore Jeffrey Sachs’ insights on economics, development, and why your pediatrician might make a better economist than most: The Corruption ParadoxSachs has a nuanced take on corruption that made me rethink my assumptions. While he’s ethically opposed to corruption (aren’t we all?), he acknowledges something counterintuitive: some corrupt places still experience significant economic growth. “Some places are so corrupt you first want to step foot in them,” Sachs explains, describing meetings where officials’ eyes glaze over discussing actual development. But then he drops this: “Other places have been corrupt for a long time. I’m thinking of New York, Washington, Lagos, Beijing and others with economic progress.” Wait, did he casually include New York and Washington in his list of corrupt-but-functional places? As someone who’s lived in several mini-major cities, this tracks. I’ve seen local officials who couldn’t organize a one-car parade preside over booming economic growth. It’s like watching someone accidentally succeed at baking while trying to make a sandwich. The key insight isn’t that corruption is good (it’s not), but that development is messier than our economic models suggest. China has grown despite corruption, not because of it. This feels important at a time when we’re quick to prescribe one-size-fits-all solutions to complex problems. The Tariff Twist: Updating Sachs’ Corruption ParadoxSpeaking of China – the world has changed since Sachs made these observations. If I were chatting with him today, I’d point to recent TikTok research showing how tariffs have disrupted his “corrupt but functional” theory. Remember when “trade war” was just history? Now the U.S. has imposed XXX% tariffs on Chinese imports, and China retaliated with YY% tariffs on American goods (numbers from today’s latest Tweet). It’s like watching divorced parents try to one-up each other at their kid’s graduation party, except the kid is the global economy. This tariff tantrum has slowed China’s growth to a projected 2025 level – practically a recession by their standards. So much for that corrupt-but-growing model. Tariffs and corruption have a toxic romance. High tariffs create new opportunities for corruption (shocking), especially with exemption systems that benefit the president’s golfing buddies. Meanwhile, the IMF warns that these tariff escalations could shrink global GDP by 0.X percentage points in 2025, which is economist-speak for “we’re all screwed.” The research suggests Sachs’ observations might need an asterisk today: corrupt economies might grow despite corruption with open trade, but add high tariffs, and that growth model looks shakier than my non-existent retirement plan. I’m left wondering what Sachs would say now. His corruption paradox still feels true, but the current tariff landscape has changed the game. Maybe it’s less “corrupt but functional” and more “corrupt but functional until a trade war.” The Doctor Will See Your Economy NowThe most fascinating part of this conversation was Sachs’ concept of “clinical economics” – an approach inspired by watching his pediatrician wife diagnose sick children at night. When a parent calls about a child with a fever, there are thousands of possible causes. Does the doctor immediately say, “It’s institutions!” or “It’s corruption!”? No, she asks targeted questions, starting with the most urgent: “Is the baby’s neck stiff?” (a potential sign of meningitis). I can’t help but contrast this with our approach to economic problems. We’re quick to diagnose entire countries with our pet economic theories without checking their vital signs. It’s like a doctor prescribing antibiotics for every patient without asking about symptoms. “I wish economists had those basic skills inbred,” Sachs laments. “It took me a long time of seeing lots of patients to see that one needs that same approach.” As someone who’s seen various economic panaceas come and go (remember when microfinance would solve global poverty?), this resonates deeply. We keep trying to force complex realities into simplistic models, then act surprised when our prescriptions fail. The Poland All-NighterSachs’ story of pulling an all-nighter to write Poland’s economic transformation plan is relatable. When asked to create a blueprint for converting Poland from communism to a market economy, he expected a couple of weeks. Instead, he was told: “I need it tomorrow morning.” “One of the great life experiences is the lessons of four years of Harvard all-nighters,” Sachs recalls. “So I pulled an all-nighter, and I wrote a plan for transforming Poland from a communist centrally-planned economy to a market economy.” I’m recalling every project I’ve procrastinated on, except instead of a blog post or expense report, Sachs was redesigning an entire nation’s economic system. The stakes were higher than my late TPS reports. The prompt he was given: “Poland’s return to Europe.” This clear vision – becoming a normal European country – provided the framework for everything else. It’s like having a north star for a nation’s transformation. Poland went from revolutionary drama to what a human rights leader called “boring” – the highest compliment. They became a normal European country, as planned. Russia lacked a clear endpoint, partly because of its geography spanning 11 time zones across the Eurasian landmass. As Sachs puts it, “Russia, 11 time zones of the Eurasian landmass, does not have a fixed focal point.” This applies beyond economics. Whether it’s a career change, a relationship, or a creative project – having a clear vision of the destination makes the journey easier. Without it, we’re just wandering around making random changes and hoping for the best (which describes my home renovation approach). I try to shoo other thoughts away (the house of cards is built on all-nighters). The Geopolitical Plot TwistHere’s where the story takes a John le Carré turn. After helping Poland transition with US support, Sachs was asked by Gorbachev and then Yeltsin to help Russia do the same. “I said exactly the same things,” Sachs explains. “And the US government kept saying, no, no way, no way. And I kept saying, but that kept working there.” Sachs took years to understand: “We didn’t want to help Russia in 1991. We wanted our unipolar world.” This is like realizing your friend gave you bad directions to a party they didn’t want you to attend. The US had the blueprint for successful transition (it worked in Poland!) but withheld it from Russia for strategic reasons. This is chilling because it suggests economic failure isn’t just bad luck or bad policy – it can be by design. As someone who attributes problems to incompetence rather than malice, this is a sobering reminder that the game is rigged. The Robot Barista Is Coming For Your JobOn a lighter note, Sachs paints a vivid picture of our automated future that made me both excited and terrified. “You don’t need baristas in Starbucks,” he explains. “We will walk in soon to a Starbucks and our iris will be scanned. And your default mode of a chocolate venti will come out automatically of a machine and you’ll take it out the other door.” But wait, it gets creepier: “They’ll predict which days you’re gonna come even, right? They’ll welcome you by name, of course, as you arrive, but we were expecting you 10 minutes late. Is everything okay, Mr. Sachs?” As someone who’s unnerved when my phone shows travel time to frequent places (how does it KNOW?), this future feels inevitable and unsettling. The barista who misspells my name is being replaced by an AI that knows my schedule better than I do. Sachs, ever the economist, sees the deeper paradox here: “As economists, we should say instinctively, it’s a great thing. Are you kidding? We’re gonna have the robots do all the work for us.” This has been humanity’s dream since we were “condemned to work in the fields 10,000 years ago in the Neolithic Revolution.” But there’s a catch: “There is something right actually, theoretically, about the argument that the demand for labor falls, the wages decline, and that can actually lead to a downward spiral in our economies.” I’m picturing a future (tomorrow) where robots make our coffee, drive our cars, and write our newsletters (wait…), while we humans… do what exactly? Sachs suggests that with proper government intervention and redistribution, everyone could benefit from this technological revolution. But that’s a big “if” given our track record with managing technological transitions. The Gorilla Lifestyle PlanIn my favorite tangent of the conversation, Sachs describes visiting gorillas in Rwanda’s Virunga National Park and having an epiphany about human labor. “What do they do all day? They play, they lie around, they eat some bamboo shoots, a little sex now and then. Basically, it’s a pretty leisurely existence.” According to anthropologists, this leisurely approach to life wasn’t so different from pre-agricultural human societies. Then came the Neolithic Revolution 10,000 years ago, and “for the next 10,000 years, people broke their backs trying to stay alive growing food.” I’m now questioning my entire work ethic. Have I been aspiring to the wrong species’ lifestyle this whole time? Should I be taking career advice from gorillas instead of LinkedIn influencers? Sachs frames our modern technological revolution as an attempt to return to this more leisurely existence, with machines doing the heavy lifting. It’s a compelling vision, though I suspect the transition might be bumpy. I’m not sure my wife will accept “living like a gorilla” as an excuse for trash rotting in the kitchen. Economics’ Fatal FlawSachs identifies a fundamental weakness in how economists approach problems: they avoid studying specific technologies or contexts in depth, preferring general principles that won’t become outdated. “Economics, we avoid that, I think, conceptually because if you study anything too specific, it’s out of date in 10 years. So we study general principles. I think that’s epistemologically the weakness of our field.” He contrasts this with biology, where Watson and Crick didn’t just say “assume n base pairs” – they specifically identified the four base pairs and the double helix structure of DNA, which scientists then studied intensively for decades. This hit me like a ton of bricks because it explains so much about why economic advice often feels disconnected from reality. Economists are trying to be physicists in a world that requires biologists – they want universal laws when what we need are detailed understandings of specific contexts. “We’re not training students that way,” Sachs laments. “We’re training them in general principles or in very fancy statistical exercises that actually miss the point.” As someone who’s watched economic debates play out in the real world, this rings painfully true. We keep trying to apply universal principles to unique situations, then wonder why our solutions don’t work. Final Thoughts: The Case for HumilityIf there’s one thread running through all of Sachs’ insights, it’s the need for humility in approaching complex problems. Whether it’s understanding corruption’s role in development, diagnosing economic ailments, or predicting the impact of automation, the answer is rarely simple or universal. The clinical economics approach – carefully examining the specific context before prescribing solutions – feels like a radical departure from how we typically approach problems. It requires admitting that we don’t have all the answers upfront, that our favorite theories might not apply in every situation, and that sometimes we need to just listen and observe before jumping to conclusions. When Predictions Miss By Miles: A Reality CheckSpeaking of humility, let’s acknowledge something economists hate talking about: how spectacularly wrong even the best predictions often turn out. Remember Sachs’ Poland-Russia comparison? Poland would become a “boring” European country, while Russia struggled mainly due to lacking a “fixed focal point.” Fast forward to today, and while Poland’s trajectory has been relatively stable, Russia’s path was completely transformed by geopolitical tensions and conflicts that few predicted. The complexity of factors affecting both economies proved far greater than anyone anticipated. Remember that iris-scanning Starbucks future Sachs described? The reality of automation has been far more nuanced. Studies show that for every robot added per 1,000 workers, wages declined by 0.42%, and employment dropped by 5.6 workers per industrial robot in local markets. But these impacts varied wildly by sector, and the government intervention Sachs suggested would manage this transition has proven less effective than hoped. And what about charter cities, the very concept mentioned in this episode’s title? These were supposed to be engines of economic growth lifting millions from poverty. The reality? Projects in Madagascar and Honduras failed due to political challenges, and many special economic zones didn’t grow faster than their national averages. The concept has largely failed to meet its transformative expectations. Then there are the “black swan” events no economic model saw coming: a global pandemic causing the worst downturn since the Great Depression, unprecedented supply chain disruptions, and inflation surges that blindsided even the best economists. I’m not pointing this out to mock Sachs or economists generally. Rather, it’s a reminder that even brilliant minds struggle with the sheer complexity of interconnected global systems. Single events trigger unexpected cascading effects, human behavior defies rational models, and the gap between theoretical policy solutions and messy real-world implementation is often wider than a California canyon. This is perhaps the most important lesson from Sachs’ conversation: not the specific predictions or policies, but the intellectual framework of humility and careful diagnosis he advocates. In a world where the frequency of “unpredictable” events seems higher than our models assume, perhaps the wisest approach isn’t having the right answers, but asking better questions. As someone who’s guilty of having strong opinions on topics I barely understand (just ask my friends who’ve endured my rants), this is a humbling reminder. Maybe the world needs fewer confident economists with universal theories and more curious ones with good diagnostic skills. In the meantime, I’ll be contemplating the gorilla lifestyle plan while my iris gets scanned for my next automated coffee order. |